|
Housing Policies in
the New Millennium
HUD Conference on Housing
Policies for the Millennium, October 3, 2000 Washington D.C. -
U.S. Department of Housing and Urban Development
Speech by Anthony
Downs, Senior Fellow, Economic
Studies
|
|
My daunting assignment is to present an overview
of what our housing policies ought to be for the New Millennium. I
cannot cover all policies, but only those I feel are most crucial.
I will begin with certain key background factors that
underlie my subsequent analysis. |
1. First, the
American housing production and urban growth processes already
provide excellent shelter opportunities for most households with
middle- and upper-incomes, except in a few very high-cost areas like
Northern California. Our housing markets are working well for most
households with money.
|
2. Second, the most
widespread and serious U.S. housing problem lies in the discrepancy
between the low incomes of many poor households and minimal costs of
"decent" housing as judged by middle-class standards. Household
incomes go right down to almost zero, but the minimal costs of
"decent" shelter level off at some amount needed to cover basic
space, plumbing, kitchen, utility, and heating needs.
|
- In 1997, 42.7% of all renter households had incomes below 50%
of their area medians, 27% had incomes below 30% of those medians
about equivalent to the poverty level and 15% had incomes below
20% of those medians.
- The 1997 fair market rent for a household of 4 was $720 per
month (derived from 15 large MSAs). That is equivalent to 90 cents
per square foot per month if such an apartment contained 800
square feet. If that is equivalent to 30% of income, then the
minimum income needed to avoid "housing poverty" was $28,800. That
is much higher than the 1997 food-based poverty level of $16,400.
In 1997, an estimated 57.3% of all renter households had incomes
below $28,800, so they were "housing poor."
- If the 27% of all renter households with incomes below $12,000
spent 30% of their incomes on rent, and if rent was 90 cents per
square foot per month as derived from fair market rents, then such
households could only afford to occupy 333 square feet. The 15% of
all renters with incomes below 20% of the area medians could
afford to occupy only 222 square feet. These unit sizes are far
below the sizes considered "decent" and required by nearly all
building codes.
- This shows that millions of American families cannot afford
ANY newly-built dwellings without spending over 30% of their
incomes for housing. Hence they are excluded from living in all
new-growth areas unless subsidized, and we do not subsidize
anywhere near all households that are eligible. The only way you
can occupy only 222 square feet is by having 3 households in one
unit!
- Clearly, low incomes comprise by far our largest "housing
problem." The best way to attack that problem is by raising
incomes of the poor. That means through programs beyond HUD's
jurisdiction, except for vouchers, which in essence increase the
money incomes of families who receive them.
|
3. A third critical
factor is that the population of the U.S. will rise by 48 million
from 2000 to 2020, and housing should be created that those people
can afford to occupy. Over one-third of these added people will be
immigrants from abroad or their children. Many will be very poor; so
they will be unable to afford new units built to our high-quality
standards without subsidies. Yet poor immigrants are not deterred
from entering our cities by high housing prices that force them to
double and triple up, because overcrowded housing is superior to
what they experience in their home areas.
- Recent economic prosperity, combined with some negative
conditions produced by growth in high-growth areas, have
intensified anti-growth feelings in many communities, especially
new suburbs. Although individual localities can slow growth within
their own borders, there is no way for individual regions or the
nation as a whole to stop or greatly slow their future growth. Yet
concern with how to cope with this growth is arising all across
the nation and will greatly effect the environments in which
future housing must be created.
- As a result, effective housing policy must be concerned with
the entire growth process, not just the building of new housing as
though it were separate from the growth process. Housing policies
must be integrated with growth
policies.
|
4. A fourth crucial
factor in housing policy is that most middle- and upper-income
households of all ethnic groups do not want to live in neighborhoods
containing any sizable number or percentage of poor people. This is
especially true of households with school-aged children. Therefore,
non-poor households withdraw from areas where many poor live and
erect barriers to the subsequent entry of the poor into their own
neighborhoods. This behavior is the foundation for the
socio-economic hierarchy of neighborhoods found in every U.S.
metropolitan area.
- Such behavior is similar to the unwillingness of most whites
to live in areas where more than 25 to 33% of the residents are
African Americans no matter what their income levels. This
underlies continuing racial segregation. Similar but less
intensive feelings are held by whites about other minorities too.
- The non-poor exclude the poor not through purely market
forces, but through local zoning and other regulations that
prevent construction of affordable units. This behavior is rooted
in the strong desire of homeowning households to protect and
increase their housing values, since housing is their greatest
financial asset. Hence suburban governments, which are almost
always dominated by homeowning voters, tend to adopt parochial
policies that aim at benefiting their own residents, without
regard to the impacts upon anyone else.
- Exclusionary zoning is reinforced by the desire of local
officials and citizens to minimize taxes by blocking land uses
that generate more local expenses than revenues. This means
housing, especially housing for people with children. So truly
affordable housing is regarded as a fiscal anathema by suburban
governments, and they all try to shunt it off onto other areas.
Yet our economy cannot run without many low-wage workers who
cannot afford "decent" units.
- These exclusionary motives are emphasized during periods of
prosperity when residents have the luxury of not worrying about
their jobs or incomes. Then they can worry about elements like
congestion and life style. Another result of prosperity has been
rising prices and rents that hurt the poor. From 1990-1999, median
home prices in the largest 21 metro areas rose an average of
33.9%.
|
5. A central, if
unintended, consequence of such exclusionary behavior is significant
concentration of the poorest households together in high-poverty
neighborhoods in central cities and older suburbs - especially poor
minority households, who are doubly excluded. Yet concentrating many
very poor people together produces adverse neighborhood environments
that reduce the life-chances of people there, compared to
environments with much more economically diverse populations. I am
convinced, and so are most big-city mayors and many HUD officials,
that we cannot improve the quality of life for the very poor without
reducing big poverty clusters.
- Such poverty concentrations have been worsened by federal and
other government policies that focused most housing assistance and
incentives on the very poorest households, in the poorest areas.
This was done in the name of humanely aiding those who needed it
most. But this policy has failed because it increased
concentration of the poorest households together, as in high-rise
public housing projects - thereby creating socially destructive
environments.
- It is time to re-align incentives created by federal policies
so they encourage greater income diversity, even if that means
giving public aid to people who are not the very poorest. For
example, more points for low income housing tax credit projects
should be given to those with moderate percentages of very poor
residents, rather than to those with the highest percentages, as
is done now.
|
6. The preceding
points show the dominant American housing development process causes
a progressive abandonment of parts of many large older cities
through growth at the suburban fringe, aggravating urban decline.
Many observers blame such urban decline on suburban sprawl, but that
conclusion is not accurate.
- Major suburban growth in U.S. metropolitan areas was, and
still is, inevitable because of population increases in those
areas, plus rising real incomes that generate desires for
low-density living. "Sprawl" is just one possible form of suburban
growth marked by very low densities, leap-frog new development,
unlimited outward extension, and automobile dominance. In the
U.S., sprawl has been so dominant that most people wrongly think
it is the same as growth.
- I have conducted extensive regression analyses that show
almost no connection between the basic traits of sprawl I
mentioned and urban decline - measured as either city population
change from 1980-1990 or by an index of decline indicators like
high crime rates, high poverty rates, etc. This surprised me.
- Further analysis convinced me that it is not the low-density
aspects of suburban growth - those which comprise sprawl - that
lead to urban decline. Rather, it is the operation of six other
basic characteristics of our development process.
(1) We
require all new housing to meet high quality standards that poor
people cannot afford without subsidies, (2) we do not provide most
of the poor with such subsidies, so few can live in new-growth
areas, (3) we encourage exclusionary suburban zoning, (4) we
engage in widespread racial segregation in almost all housing
markets, (5) we maintain major obstacles to redevelopment of older
core areas, and (6) we have social values that encourage
households to move to higher-status neighborhoods when their
incomes rise. These factors - not low density - are the reasons
why our growth causes poverty concentrations.
- This is an important conclusion because it implies that
continued growth would still lead to concentrated poverty even if
we shifted from sprawl to much more compact forms of growth -
unless we altered those six basic characteristics. And
concentrated poverty would still generate withdrawal of the middle
class to the suburbs, which aggravates urban decline. In fact, the
poor themselves often move out of high-poverty areas once they get
higher incomes.
|
Now let us turn to
conclusions about housing policy from these background
factors.
1. My first conclusion is that by far the most
important housing policies are being set by local governments - not
the federal government. True, the federal government influences the
financial climate that affects housing affordability and production.
But local governments set the rules of housing quality and density
that really determine the amount of housing built and where
different income groups will live. And those local policies are
mainly determined by the parochial and exclusionary perspectives of
suburban homeowners, as described earlier. This perpetuates poverty
concentrations.
- Therefore, the most important thing the federal government can
do to improve housing opportunities for the poor is to exert
influence on local governments to be less parochial in deciding
what types of housing can be built where. This would require HUD
and Congress to create incentives for local and state governments
to modify their currently exclusionary behavior towards housing.
- Examples have already been created by EPA and DOT - the latter
in the form of Metropolitan Planning Organizations. Both require
each metropolitan area to establish a regional planning agency
that considers area-wide plans before the federal government will
provide any funds to any governments in the region. HUD could make
its financial aids similar contingent on regional planning.
- Possible goals would be (1) to require each metropolitan
region to establish "fair share" allocations of low-cost housing
among its communities, (2) to allow owners of single-family homes
of a certain size to create accessory apartments in their homes
even if the local government does not permit it, (3) to require
every community to zone some land for multi-family housing, and
(4) to expand use of vouchers to encourage the "moving to
opportunity" program. At the very least, HUD could make planning
grants to local governments within regions where all such
governments agreed to develop a voluntary regional plan
- Because suburban homeowners form a majority of voters in the
U.S., Congress will be reluctant to permit such a policy. Yet HUD
should press to get one because HUD cannot reduce inner-city
decline without affecting the growth process as a whole, which
means affecting local suburban growth policies.
|
2. A second key
goal of housing policy should be to deconcentrate existing
high-poverty enclaves in two ways. One is by using vouchers to give
households voluntary opportunities to move to middle-income
neighborhoods. The other is to encourage greater income diversity in
poor neighborhoods, including in public housing. These are already
present goals of HUD policy that should be promoted more strongly.
- This approach contradicts the desire of
middle-and-upper-income households to isolate themselves from the
poor. Since the non-poor are much more numerous and more powerful
than the poor, society has resisted nearly all attempts to
deconcentrate the poor by integrating them into more affluent
communities.
- I have long believed in my heart that we in the
middle-and-upper-income groups cannot ultimately upgrade our
poorer brothers and sisters at arm's length, but must somehow
share our neighborhoods with them if we want to create truly equal
opportunities in our society. But this is distinctly a minority
viewpoint strongly resisted by the vast majority of non-poor
Americans, and by many poor.
|
3. My third key
goal is striking a better balance between aid to homeowners "mainly
as tax benefits" and aid to poor renters by greatly increasing the
latter. In the 1990s, HUD placed much more emphasis on promoting
home ownership than aiding low-income renters, even though the
latter have more serious housing problems. Homeownership rates have
risen notably, and that is good. But today builders are putting up
many houses costing $2 to $3 million. It is ludicrously unjust to
give those buyers tax benefits of as much as $58,500 per year while
not providing any assistance to most eligible low-income renters. We
do not need to encourage more mansions.
- Changing interest and property tax deductions to tax credits
would be much fairer without eliminating big tax benefits to
homeownership. This would either shift more benefits to less
affluent homeowners or save money. The money thus saved could be
allocated to greater assistance to low-income renters.
- More federal money should be spent on aiding low-income
renters - mainly as vouchers and as aid to the rehabilitation of
older units. HUD should also consider setting higher fair market
rents in suburban markets with high housing prices to enable
Section 8 households to live there; the present single-rent policy
in all parts of a metropolitan area further encourages
concentration of the poor.
|
4. Because it is
politically impossible to focus all federal aids on deconcentrating
existing poverty enclaves, we should also invest notable resources
in improving conditions there. We will be unable to deconcentrate
even a majority of existing high-poverty areas within any short
time, so we should not ignore those still there.
- However, we should recognize that efforts to up-grade such
areas are not likely to be effective, unless many non-poor
residents can be attracted to live there. Billions of dollars have
been spent to encourage Community Development Corporations and
empowerment zones to upgrade their entire neighborhoods. But few
have succeeded, though they have built many new housing units. It
is time to stop wasting such aid by focusing more of it on
encouraging diversity
- But that means devoting public funds to providing incentives
to persons other than the very poorest. This is a politically
controversial but necessary strategy that most city mayors are now
promoting because they realize it is necessary.
|
5. Another goal of
federal housing policy should be closer integration of land-use
planning, transportation planning, and environmental planning since
each type of planning is heavily influenced by the others in a
process of mutual causation. In theory, the Departments of Housing
and Urban Development and Transportation should be merged into one
federal agency. It could be called either THUD because of its
heavily influence, or maybe HUDAT just for fun. That department
should then require each metropolitan area to develop some type of
coordinated affordable housing and ground transportation plan as a
prerequisite to receiving federal funding.
- Transportation planning is generally not done with full
recognition of its impacts upon land use, and vice versa. The U.S.
and state DOTs do not realize they are not just building roads but
creating the future skeletons of entire metro areas.
- However, it would not be possible to combine these departments
without major changes in the committee structures of Congress. Yet
Congress is far more resistant to reform than any other
institution in America. And trying to closely integrate the
actions of separate federal agencies is usually a vain exercise.
- As a starter, HUD should clean up its own act a bit. For
example, HUD's Economic Development Initiative financed a hotel in
Huntington Beach without inquiring whether the low-wage workers to
be hired could afford to live there, or would have to drive miles
to work. No such grants should be approved without examining their
impacts upon local housing and transportation requirements.
|
6. A final policy
recommendation is that the federal government should continue to
promote economic policies that keep interest rates low and labor
markets tight. Low rates make it easier to build more housing, and
tight labor markets raise the incomes of many low-income workers.
The long run of nine years of prosperity has done more for the
economies of our cities than any other federal policies of any
types.
|
As we consider
these policy recommendations, one enormous obstacle to achieving
them emerges. It is the fact that present institutional arrangements
in housing markets and growth processes favor the
middle-and-upper-income majority at the expense of the low-income
minority - especially low-income ethnic minorities. For example,
concentration of poverty in older core-areas permits more affluent
households to live in neighborhoods mostly free from problems
associated with poverty. That is what they like and want.
1.
In short, democracy is working, because the majority has created and
sustained arrangements which benefit it and which its members
therefore do not want to change. For decades, it has proven
extremely difficult to persuade that majority to alter those
institutional arrangements which benefit it by imposing high costs
upon the poor. Appealing to their sympathy for the poor has had only
modest impacts.
|
2. But now the
suburban majority itself is beginning to complain about some of the
costs of the growth processes it has generated, especially traffic
congestion. The challenge to those of us trying to implement the
policies I have described is to use these feelings of
dissatisfaction to achieve institutional changes - such as at least
some regional planning mechanisms - that might help remove some of
the unfairness and ineffectiveness of our present housing and
development processes.
|
3. Such appeals to
the self-interest of the majority should include pointing out two
consequences of the failure to up-grade the skills and incomes of
people now living in concentrated poverty areas or to permit more of
them to move to the suburbs.
- First, such failure will weaken the ability of those people to
buy the suburban homes of the current white baby-boomers when they
or their children want to sell. The potential market will then
consist heavily of minority households now living in cities. But
those possible buyers cannot maintain future home values of the
present residents if they have little money.
- Second, if low-wage workers essential to both business and
residential areas have to live far from where the jobs are located
because there is no affordable housing nearby, then both traffic
congestion and air pollution will rise, reducing the quality of
life for the affluent households who can afford to live there.
In conclusion, I hope we will recognize that
future housing policies and future metropolitan growth policies are
inextricably intertwined, and cannot be treated separately. If so,
we can perhaps use the growing awareness among even
middle-and-upper-income households that our growth policies must be
changed to achieve major improvements in our housing policies in the
new millennium.
| |